You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/inflation_history.md
+14-12Lines changed: 14 additions & 12 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -13,22 +13,22 @@ kernelspec:
13
13
14
14
# Price Level Histories
15
15
16
-
This lecture offers some scraps of historical evidence about fluctuations in the level of aggregate price indexes.
16
+
This lecture offers some scraps of historical evidence about fluctuations in levels of aggregate price indexes.
17
17
18
18
The rate of growth of the price level is called **inflation** in the popular press and in discussions among central bankers and treasury officials.
19
19
20
20
The price level is measured in units of domestic currency per units of a representative bundle of consumption goods.
21
21
22
-
Thus, in the US, it is measured in dollars in month $t$ or year $t$ per unit of the consumption bundle.
22
+
Thus, in the US, the price level at $t$ is measured in dollars in month $t$ or year $t$ per unit of the consumption bundle.
23
23
24
-
Until the early 20th century, throughout much of the west, although price levels fluctuated year to year,
24
+
Until the early 20th century, throughout much of the west, although price levels fluctuated from year to year,
25
25
they didn't have much of a trend.
26
26
27
27
Thus, they tended to end a century at close to a level at which they started it.
28
28
29
29
Things were different in the 20th century, as we shall see in this lecture.
30
30
31
-
This lecture will set the stage for some sequel that present a particular theory that some economists use to
31
+
This lecture will set the stage for some subsequent lecture about a particular theory that economists use to
32
32
think about determinants of the price level.
33
33
34
34
@@ -48,6 +48,8 @@ The four countries are
48
48
49
49
In the present context, the phrase hard currency means that the countries were on a commodity-money standard: money consisted of gold and silver coins that circulated at values largely determined by the weights of their gold and silver contents.
50
50
51
+
(Under a gold or silver standard, some money also consisted of "warehouse certificates" that represented paper claims on gold or silver coins. Bank notes issued by the government or private banks can be viewed as examples of such "warehouse certificate".)
52
+
51
53
The data we want to study data originally appeared in a graph on page 35 of {cite}`sargent2002big`.
52
54
53
55
@@ -97,12 +99,13 @@ ax.legend()
97
99
ax.set_ylabel('Index 1913 = 100')
98
100
ax.set_xlim(xmin=1600)
99
101
plt.tight_layout()
102
+
fig.text(.5, .0001, "Price Levels", ha='center')
100
103
plt.show()
101
104
```
102
105
103
106
We say "most years" because there were temporary lapses from the gold or silver standard.
104
107
105
-
By staring at the graph carefully, you might be able to guess when these temporary lapses occurred, because they were periods in which price levels rose markedly from average values during more typical years.
108
+
By staring at the graph carefully, you might be able to guess when these temporary lapses occurred, because they were also times during which price levels rose markedly from what had been average values during more typical years.
106
109
107
110
* 1791-1797 in France (the French revolution)
108
111
* 1776-1793 in the US (the US War for Independence from Great Britain)
@@ -120,8 +123,7 @@ Two other features of the figure attracted the attention of leading economists s
120
123
121
124
* that is, society paid a high "opportunity cost" for using gold and silver as coins; gold and silver could instead be used as valuable jewelry and also as an industrial input
122
125
123
-
Keynes and Fisher argued that there was a socially efficient way to achieve a price level that would
124
-
be at least as well anchored, and would also exhibit less year-to-year short-term fluctuations.
126
+
Keynes and Fisher proposed what they suggested would be a socially more efficient way to achieve a price level that would be at least as firmly anchored, and would also exhibit less year-to-year short-term fluctuations.
125
127
126
128
In particular, they argued that a well-managed central bank could achieve price level stability by
127
129
@@ -132,7 +134,7 @@ Thus, the waste from using gold and silver as coins prompted John Maynard Keyne
132
134
133
135
A paper fiat money system disposes of all reserves behind a currency.
134
136
135
-
In doing so, it also eliminates an automatic supply mechanism constraining the price level.
137
+
But notice that in doing so, it also eliminates an automatic supply mechanism constraining the price level.
136
138
137
139
A low-inflation paper fiat money system replaces that automatic mechanism with an enlightened government that commits itself to limit the quantity of a pure token, no-cost currency.
138
140
@@ -143,7 +145,7 @@ We'll show a version of the complete graph that originally appeared on page 35
143
145
144
146
The graph shows logarithms of price levels our four "hard currency" countries from 1600 to 2000.
145
147
146
-
We didn't need to take logarithms in our earlier graphs that had stopped in 1914 -- we use logarithms now because we want also to fit observations after 1914 in the same graph as the earlier observations.
148
+
Allthough we didn't have to use logarithms in our earlier graphs that had stopped in 1914 -- we use logarithms now because we want also to fit observations after 1914 in the same graph as the earlier observations.
147
149
148
150
All four of the countries eventually permanently left the gold standard by modifying their monetary and fiscal policies in several ways, starting the outbreak of the Great War in 1914.
fig.text(.5, .0001, "Logs of Price Levels", ha='center')
166
169
plt.show()
167
170
```
168
171
@@ -179,8 +182,7 @@ The breadth and length of the inflationary experiences of the twentieth century,
179
182
180
183
## Ends of Four Big Inflations
181
184
182
-
Monetary and fiscal authorities' struggles to replicate price level stability with a paper money standard
183
-
were vividly on display in the wake of World War I, which ended in November 1918.
185
+
In the wake of World War I, which ended in November 1918, monetary and fiscal authorities struggled to achieve price level stability without being on a gold or silver standard.
184
186
185
187
We present four graphs from "The Ends of Four Big Inflations" from chapter 3 of {cite}`sargent2013rational`.
186
188
@@ -194,7 +196,7 @@ The graphs depict logarithms of price levels during the early post World War I y
194
196
We have added logarithms of the exchange rates vis a vis the US dollar to each of the four graphs
195
197
from chapter 3 of {cite}`sargent2013rational`.
196
198
197
-
Data underlying our graphs appear in the tables in an appendix to chapter 3 of {cite}`sargent2013rational`.
199
+
Data underlying our graphs appear in tables in an appendix to chapter 3 of {cite}`sargent2013rational`.
198
200
We have transcribed all of these data into a spreadsheet `chapter_3.xls` that we read into Pandas.
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/long_run_growth.md
+2-2Lines changed: 2 additions & 2 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -18,7 +18,7 @@ kernelspec:
18
18
19
19
Adam Tooze's account of the geopolitical precedents and antecedents of World War I includes a comparison of how Gross National Products of European Great Powers had evolved during the 70 years preceding 1914 (see chapter 1 of {cite}`Tooze_2014`).
20
20
21
-
We report a version of Tooze's graph later in this lecture.
21
+
We construct a version of Tooze's graph later in this lecture.
22
22
23
23
Looking at his graph and how it set the geopolitical stage for "the American (20th) century" naturally
24
24
tempts one to want a counterpart to his graph for 2014 or later.
0 commit comments